| |
|
|
Funding
OPEB Liabilities: A Proposal for the Automotive Industry
By B.
Anthony Billings and Randolph Paschke
AUGUST 2007 - American
automobile manufacturing is facing significant challenges: increased
competition in the marketplace; macroeconomic challenges related
to oil prices and supply; and accounting challenges related to
recent standards regarding other postemployment benefits (OPEB).
OPEB is a major concern for the private sector, but it is an enormous
issue for the automotive industry, with its large obligations
for retiree health benefits. It is estimated that for the 337
companies in the Standard & Poor’s (S&P) 500 that
have OPEB obligations, the funding ratio is around 27% (versus
88% for pensions). For the 282 companies with the most complete
financial records, the unfunded OPEB liability in 2005 was estimated
at $292 billion versus an unfunded pension liability of $150 billion.
The OPEB liability is concentrated in Ford Motor Company and General
Motors Corporation; their combined unfunded liability of $94 billion
represents 32% of the S&P 500’s total.
“The
state of OPEB is extremely unsettling,” wrote S&P analyst
Howard Silverblatt in a December 2005 press release. Unlike pensions,
which are regulated, there exists no legal requirement to create
a trust entity to fund current or future OPEB costs, S&P pointed
out. The ratings agency also observed that tax treatments and
credits set up specifically to encourage pension funding do not
exist for OPEB costs. S&P further noted that 88% of pension
obligations are set aside in trusts, compared with only 22% for
OPEB obligations.
The OPEB
debate has so far focused on trying to reduce retiree benefits
or increase retiree contributions. Obviously, neither of these
options is politically popular. Dealing with the OPEB liability
may also force companies to reduce investment in important, but
discretionary, programs. The most notable example is investment
in alternative-energy vehicles that can be more competitive in
a market of rising oil prices and political appeals for energy
independence. For the U.S. economy as a whole, one concern is
that any reduction in healthcare coverage will place further burdens
on the Medicare system. What is clear is that the combination
of addressing the OPEB obligation and the need for more competitive
automobiles with energy-efficient designs may be the most significant
challenge the industry has encountered. It is worth asking if
it is a challenge that U.S. automakers cannot solve without help.
One option
for funding OPEB liabilities, advanced funding, uses an entity
for employers to build an asset base to offset the accrued liabilities
and thus provide payment of the benefits as they come due in future
years. As the asset base builds up and the funding ratio increases,
a larger share of the plan’s revenues derives from investment
income, while contributions decline. This has been the result
of pension trusts in the U.S. over the last century. S&P reports
that reasonably well funded defined-benefit pension plans receive
60% to 70% of total revenues from investment income.
How can companies
like GM and Ford advance-fund their OPEB liabilities and at the
same time continue to invest additional resources into developing
new energy-saving automobiles? The authors propose the use of
government-guaranteed bonds as a means of stopping the financial
hemorrhaging of American automakers that are burdened by OPEB
liabilities.
Use
of Federal Guarantee Programs
Many national
governments, including the United States, support a wide range
of activities through credit guarantee programs. Although used
sparingly in the private sector, the most notable loan guarantee
program to date was the bailout of the Chrysler Corporation in
1980. The U.S. government provided Chrysler with $1.5 billion
in government-guaranteed debt (GGD) instruments to help the firm
achieve financial stability. By 1983, Chrysler paid off the loan
with a return of approximately $350 million to the U.S. government.
More recently, GGD instruments have been used to subsidize the
airline industry after September 11, 2001. Other notable objectives
have included the financing of rural cable television, electrification,
rural utilities, and similar types of public infrastructure. Other
programs include the Small Business Administration, the Small
Business Investment Companies program, and the Export-Import Bank
program.
Loan guarantees
lower the default risk to lenders by shifting credit risks to
the government, thereby lowering the interest cost for the borrower.
Funds obtained through GGD loans often would not have been approved
by lenders or would have been made at higher interest rates. Because
lenders charge higher interest rates for riskier loans, the differences
in the market rate of interest and the subsidized interest rate
provide an arbitrage opportunity for the borrower. The arbitrage
opportunity arises because the federal government can borrow funds
and absorb risks more cheaply than most private entities. From
2002 to 2006, the federal government guaranteed approximately
$495.6 billion in loans annually. Moreover, subsidized loans generally
have more flexible regulations than alternative lending institutions
and are exempt from state and local taxes.
Considering
that federal guarantees of bonds have been used successfully to
fund a variety of activities at minimal costs to the Treasury,
the authors propose that qualified companies be allowed to use
GGD to fund legacy costs, as well as for the development of advanced
technology for fuel-efficient vehicles and certain of their components.
The obvious benefit from this approach would be enhanced liquidity,
less expensive financing to produce fuel-saving technologies,
and more cost certainty for retirement benefits. Such a program
would allow companies to use the arbitrage benefit from such loans
to compete with foreign competitors without resorting to direct
subsidies from the U.S. government.
The subsidy
cost of GGD normally depends on the probability of default on
proceeds from any related collateral and the fees paid by debtors.
For GGD, the risk of default is negligible and the securities
trade in a narrow spread to Treasury bonds. The evidence shows
that the default risk of existing loan guarantee programs varies
widely. Most programs have default rates of less than 2%, while
others are as high as 20%. The challenge is to structure the loan
guarantee program in a way to provide as much flexibility as possible
for the debtor so that the arbitrage benefit is sufficient to
earn a rate of return at least equal to the entity’s internal
rate of return. Qualified programs should demonstrate social benefits
in the form of helping to preserve and extend employment (and,
hence, enhance employment tax receipts) and reduce the risk of
pension-fund defaults. GGD instruments offer flexibility with
respect to size, fixed or callable maturities, as well as floating
or fixed interest rates.
Estimation
of Arbitrage Opportunity
For purposes
of analysis, companies’ arbitrage is measured as the excess
of a firm’s cost of debt compared to the AAA bond rate.
Cost of debt is derived by dividing interest expenses for financial
reporting purposes by outstanding debt (see the Sidebar
for details). Data for several original equipment manufacturers
(OEM) over the 2000–2004 period are extracted from several
sources. The authors used the AAA interest rates on corporate
bonds as a proxy for the subsidized cost of GGD instruments, based
on the assumption that the implicit government guarantee reduces
the risk of default for such bonds to a risk equivalent to AAA
bonds. Lawrence J. White (“Fannie Mae, Freddie Mac, and
Housing Finance: Why True Privatization Is Good Public Policy,”
Policy Analysis: No. 528) provides support for the notion
that AAA rates are good indicators of GGD instrument costs. W.
Scott Frame and Lawrence J. White (“Regulating Housing GSEs:
Thoughts on Institutional Structure and Authorities,” Federal
Reserve Bank of Atlanta Economic Review, Second Quarter 2004)
also note that without the implicit government guarantee, GGD
instrument ratings would fall within the range of A and AA bonds.
To account
for seasonality, the two-year moving average of interest expense
was divided by the two-year moving average of outstanding debt
to obtain companies’ interest cost. As shown in the Exhibits,
the companies examined were automobile manufacturers and automobile
parts suppliers. Data points used in the estimation were extracted
from SEC filings during 2000–2004 and were supplemented
by bond yield data from several sources (missing data points are
designated as “na”). Exhibit
1 presents estimates of the arbitrage opportunity amounts,
based on the replacement of existing debt only. Column H, however,
shows the additional arbitrage amount that could be earned by
increasing debt levels to the industry average debt-to-asset ratio.
Column E shows the annual arbitrage amount and Column F shows
the amounts accumulated over the ensuing five years, based on
the internal rate of return on voluntary employee beneficiary
association (VEBA) assets.
The annual
amounts in Column F are derived by adding the computed arbitrage
amount in each year to the time value of the prior year’s
Column F amount. For this purpose, the average internal rate of
return for firms with VEBA information was used for nonpublic
companies. Unlike Exhibit 1, Exhibit
2 presents arbitrage opportunity amounts based on the excess
of interest costs tied to each firm’s bond rating over the
yield of the applicable 30-year Treasury bond. Both the Exhibit
1 and Exhibit 2 amounts are calculated based on total outstanding
debt. As shown, some companies would not benefit under the proposed
policy, because their interest costs are lower than the interest
cost on the applicable agency debt.
Implications
The computed
arbitrage amounts would provide enhanced liquidity from which
the automotive companies can fund a variety of programs without
adding significant risk to their balance sheet. These available
funds could be used to partially offset the OPEB amounts, and
the remaining amount could be earmarked to fund programs with
public benefits, such as research and development into alternative
energy sources.
The authors
propose that any GGD for U.S. automotive companies be tied to
key activities like funding new investments in advanced technology
for fuel-efficient vehicles and alternative-fuel vehicles for
domestic energy independence. New investments could be defined
in a way to ensure the related research—or production would
take place in the United States and generate American jobs. The
use of available funds for the development and production of advanced-technology
vehicles and technology to lower domestic demand for foreign oil
would go a long way in achieving energy security and in financially
stabilizing the auto industry. Such activities would have secondary
benefits in the form of helping to preserve and extend employment
(and hence enhance employment tax receipts), along with reducing
the risk of pension-fund defaults.
B.
Anthony Billings, PhD, is a professor of accounting at
Wayne State University, Detroit. Randolph Paschke, CPA,
is the chair of the department of accounting, also at Wayne State
University. |
|