| |
|
|
Ethics
of Options Repricing and Backdating
Banishing Greed from Corporate Governance and Management
By
Cecily Raiborn, Marcos Massoud, Roselyn Morris, and Chuck Pier
OCTOBER 2007
- Just when it seemed that America’s corporate scandals had
tapered off and public trust in executives was beginning to rebound,
the media revealed two techniques that corporations were using to
enhance management pay packages: the repricing and the backdating
of stock options. Stock options have been used as a means of paying
top-level employees since approximately 1957; they became extremely
popular in the early 1980s for employees in the high-tech start-up
companies of Silicon Valley. Stock
Options
Stock options
allow employees to purchase a particular number of common shares
of company stock at a specified price over a specified time period.
The option or “strike” price was commonly set at the
market price at the date of the option grant. Tying the option
price to the market price benefited both the issuing company and
the employee at the grant date: The company did not have to record
any compensation expense for accounting purposes upon issuance;
the employee did not receive a taxable benefit upon issuance and
needed to pay taxes only when the exercised options were sold
in the future. In the wake of FASB’s issuance of Statement
of Financial Accounting Standards (SFAS) 123(R), Share-Based
Payment, all stock options must be recognized as compensation
expense based on the option’s fair value on the grant date.
Even options with a strike price set at or below the stock’s
fair-market value on the grant date carry some value, and compensation
expense must be estimated by the use of an option-pricing model.
Options were
commonly issued to supplement the amount of executive non–performance-based
cash compensation above the tax-allowed $1 million deductibility
level, to provide executives with an “owner perspective,”
or to incentivize executives to work for (or remain at) an organization
that was currently cash poor but had strong future prospects.
Essentially, stock options were designed to reward current performance
with a future benefit when executives neither needed nor desired
additional current cash. Because stock options could be cashed
in and the shares subsequently sold, there always existed a motivation
for executives with options to quickly boost the stock price,
through fair means or foul. As some recent corporate scandals
show, foul often meant manipulating financial statements to increase
net income and, concurrently, stock prices. In addition to financial
statement shenanigans, net income could also be increased by firing
workers and closing plants—tactics well known to Al Dunlap,
especially during his tenure as Sunbeam’s chairman of the
board. In other words, it is possible for executives to engineer
opportunities for their stock options to rise in value.
Repricing
Stock Options
When stock
prices rise above a given option price, the expectation is that
the managers who received such options will exercise them and
become larger shareholders in the corporation. Such holdings should
motivate executives to have a greater interest in making the entity
ever more profitable, because personal and corporate performance
objectives are aligned. The bull market of the 1990s brought substantial
value to stock options, but when the market began a downturn,
investor value dropped substantially. Although investor value
dropped with share prices, the average CEO total compensation
in American companies was higher in 2002 than in 1999 (“Leaders:
Running Out of Options; Pay for Performance,” The Economist,
December 11, 2004). In other words, executive-owners continued
to benefit from huge pay packages while investor-owners suffered
from the downturn in the value of their stock portfolios. At least
some decrease in portfolio values was a direct result of the market’s
reaction to the financial scandals created by the executive-owners
of corporations.
As stock
prices declined, the value of executives’ stock options
also fell. In many cases, the market price fell below the option
price, meaning the option is “underwater” or “out
of the money,” making the original compensation benefit
worthless.
One solution
that some companies adopted was to reprice previously granted
stock options to a price below the current market price. Disclosure
of repricings for stock options held by “named executive
officers” (generally the CEO and the other four most highly
compensated executives) is required under Regulation S-K Item
402(i). In 2000, FASB Interpretation (FIN) 44, Accounting
for Certain Transactions Involving Stock Compensation, determined
that such repricings would require variable accounting treatment
from the modification date. (Instead of repricing the options
specifically, a company may also engage in “synthetic”
or “6&1” repricing, which has no current income
statement effect. In this technique, the company cancels the underwater
options and replaces them with new options six months and one
day later; the new options are set at the then-current market
price.)
This variable
accounting treatment would create a negative income statement
impact equal to the number of repriced shares multiplied by the
difference between the original option price and the year-end
market price; the treatment would continue for each year until
the options were exercised, forfeited, or cancelled. Therefore,
the more the stock’s market price rises after the repricing,
the greater the reduction in future earnings. The
executive benefits from the reduction in option price, but the
company and the other non–stock-option-holding investors
face a lowered net income, which, in turn, could generate a lower
share price. Repricings effectively reward executives for corporate
difficulties, rather than hold them accountable. In addition,
if the company has to acquire treasury stock in the future to
satisfy option holders upon exercise, the market activity could
create an even higher price and greater gains to the exercising
employee. Such gains would benefit all stockholders but could
make potential new investors less able to acquire the higher-priced
stock.
It is important
to note that a company does not have to reprice all outstanding
options, but “may tailor [its] repricings to include or
exclude certain options and/or groups of employees or optionees”
(P. Garth Gartrell, “Stock Options and Equity Compensation
after the ‘Crash,’” Journal of Deferred
Compensation, Fall 2001). If options for high-level executives
were repriced while those of lower-level employees were not (or
were not repriced to the same degree), one might view such discriminatory
treatment as unethical, given that the executives should be held
responsible for the downturn in earnings that presumably precipitated
the downturn in stock price.
Boards of
directors have defended the repricing of executive stock options
by stating that it helps retain executives who are essential to
company performance. The authors believe that the issue that must
be addressed in the face of this logic is how essential such executives
actually are if they were the people in charge during the market
decline. There is some evidence that the performance and retention
rationales behind repricing are flawed. First, results from one
study spanning five decades showed “no evidence of a systematic
relationship between equity and firm performance” (Catherine
M. Daily and Dan R. Dalton, “The Problem with Equity Compensation,”
Journal of Business Strategy, July/August 2002). Second,
three separate studies indicated that “over the two-year
period after repricing, CEO turnover [was] approximately twice
as high for repricing firms compared to a matched group of firms
that did not reprice” (Dan R. Dalton and Catherine M. Dalton,
“On the Decision to Reprice Stock Options: Almost Never,”
Journal of Business Strategy, vol. 26, no. 3, 2005).
Backdating
Stock Options
As discussed
earlier, when stock options are issued, the strike price is typically
set to equal the market price at the option date to avoid recording
compensation expense and the incurring taxable income to the recipient.
The results of a study by Erik Lie (“On the Timing of CEO
Stock Option Awards,” Management Science, May 2005)
suggested that many stock option awards made during the period
1992 to 2002 were actually “timed retroactively”—dated
to coincide with a low price, which then rose after the grant
date. In 2006, Charles Forelle and James Bandler (“The Perfect
Payday,” Wall Street Journal, March 18, 2006) reported
that all six of the option packages granted to Affiliated Computer
Services Inc.’s CEO Jeffrey Rich from 1995 to 2002 were
dated at the bottom of a steep drop in stock price, with the odds
of such an occurrence “around one in a billion.” The
SEC decided to look into the issue of backdating option prices,
and by mid-2007 more than 140 companies were under investigation.
The companies involved range from the low-tech to the high-tech,
from the start-up to the well-established. Some companies came
forth voluntarily; some were subpoenaed. Many are conducting their
own internal investigations. It seems that the practice of backdating
has been prevalent but hidden for quite a while.
Prior to
2002, a company was not required to report its issuance of stock
options until after the close of the fiscal year, providing ample
time to backdate options. Section 403 of the Sarbanes-Oxley Act
(SOX) tightened the reporting requirements for the issuance of
executive stock options; companies now must report options on
Form 4 within two days of their issuance. This requirement should
significantly reduce the opportunity for backdating, if companies
comply with the new regulation. However, a recent study found
that, from September to November 2002 (SOX was enacted in July
2002), one-fifth of companies were still not meeting the two-day
requirement (Randall Heron and Erik Lie, “Does Backdating
Explain the Stock Price Pattern Around Executive Stock Option
Grants?” Journal of Financial Economics, February
2007). One would hope that such delays have been resolved since
that study was conducted.
Another troublesome
issue has arisen in companies’ response to backdated stock
options. According to Charles Forelle (“Executives Get Bonuses
as Firms Reprice Options,” Wall Street Journal,
January 20–21, 2006), some companies (such as KLA-Tencor
Corp.) that engaged in backdating have opted to adjust the executive
options to reflect the price actually existing on the grant award
dates, but have provided the executive with a cash “bonus”
for the amount lost from repricing. Such a tactic could be seen
as an extra reward to the executive, who obtains cash even if
the stock prices fall from the bad publicity resulting from backdating:
a win-win situation for the executive and a lose-lose situation
for other shareholders.
Rather than
accepting executive greed or poor organizational ethics as the
crux of the problem, blame is now being partially placed on the
same 1993 tax law that caused a surge in stock options by limiting
the deductibility of executives’ non–performance-based
cash compensation to $1 million. According to SEC Chairman Christopher
Cox (who was a member of Congress when the 1993 law was enacted)
and Public Company Accounting Oversight Board (PCAOB) Chairman
Mark Olson, this law “unintentionally sparked a trend …
for companies to get more creative with incentives for their executives”
(Marie Leone and Sarah Johnson, “Backdating Blamed on 1993
Tax Rule,” CFO, September 6, 2006, www.cfo.com).
Some U.S. senators are now contending that the law should be repealed,
that companies should be allowed to pay executives any amount,
fully deductible for tax purposes.
It is obvious
to the authors that the law did, in fact, prompt many companies
to use stock options as a form of noncash compensation, but to
infer that this justifies the backdating of options seems a huge
leap of logic. Whether all cash compensation of CEOs should be
tax deductible is an issue that should be addressed on its independent
merits, or lack thereof, with a clear eye toward acknowledging
the massive discrepancy that exists between worker pay and executive
compensation in the United States. According to a BusinessWeek
survey of large U.S. corporations, CEO pay rose from 107 times
that of an average worker in 1990 to 431 times that of an average
worker in 2004, with a multiple of 525 in 2000 (United for a Fair
Economy, The Growing Divide: Inequality and the Roots of Economic
Insecurity, February 2006; www.faireconomy.org/econ/workshops/
workshop_pdfs/GD_Charts1.9.pdf#search=
%22%20CEO%20pay%22). These relationships do not seem to indicate
that the backdating of stock options was somehow necessary to
provide a “reasonable” wage for CEOs!
The problem
with options backdating is not just the improper benefit provided
to the executives receiving the options, but also the detriment
caused to other investors and to the organization’s reputation.
One study showed that backdating stock options added approximately
$600,000 to the average executive’s pay at 48 companies
between 2000 and 2004, but the market value decline in those companies
since the investigations into the practice began has been approximately
$500 million, or more than $10 per share, on average (Eric Dash,
“Report Estimates the Costs of a Stock Options Scandal,”
New York Times, September 6, 2006). In addition, companies
are now facing potentially massive restatements that could reduce
reported income, which would likely trigger further downturns
in stock value. Shareholder and pension-fund lawsuits have been
launched against some companies and are on the horizon for others.
During 2006, despite a large decline in the total number of class-action
lawsuits involving securities issues from the previous year, 20
suits related to options backdating were filed against companies
(Nathan Koppel, “Legal Bear: Stock Class-Actions Fall,”
Wall Street Journal, January 2, 2007). Companies providing
corporate directors and officers (D&O) insurance are also
asking questions, attempting to determine whether premiums are
sufficient or, in the event of illegal activities, whether coverage
is in effect.
Spring-Loading
and Bullet-Dodging
Because the
SOX disclosure requirements make it essentially impossible to
backdate stock options, some companies have turned to two other
tactics to increase executive pay: spring-loading and bullet-dodging.
Spring-loading refers to the practice of issuing options shortly
before announcing good news to investors; bullet-dodging refers
to delaying an option grant until after bad news has been reported.
Some people are criticizing these techniques as being a form of
insider trading or trading in the company stock by using nonpublic
information that, if known by the general investing public, would
significantly influence the company’s stock price. SEC Commissioner
Paul Atkins (“Remarks Before the International Corporate
Governance Network 11th Annual Conference,” July 6, 2006;
www.sec.gov/news/speech/2006/spch070606psa.htm)
disagreed that these tactics are equivalent to insider trading,
in part because corporate boards always have “inside information”
but cannot predict how the news will affect the investing public.
Atkins believes that opportune timing of options grants merely
provides the best benefit to the grantee at the least cost to
the corporation.
Potentially,
however, the issue could be viewed as an extension of Regulation
Fair Disclosure, issued by the SEC in August 2000. Regulation
FD’s stated purpose is to curb selective disclosures by
corporate boards and executives of material, nonpublic information
to favorite research analysts or portfolio managers before giving
the information to the general public. Technically, the timing
of options grants does not fall under Regulation FD; however,
a case could be made that the end results are similar: Someone
or some group benefits to the exclusion of others. In the case
of selective disclosures, certain analysts and their clients benefit;
in the case of option timing, certain inside executives benefit.
Using
Indexing to Determine Option Price
Many people
might argue that backdating and repricing have occurred because
companies thought it was unfair to penalize executives for recent
downturns in stock prices that were due to macroeconomic pressures
and industry fluctuations beyond the control of CEOs. While backdating
and repricing present questionable behaviors by corporate compensation
committees, an alternative methodology—indexing stock options—might
be viewed as more fair and effective in rewarding the highest-performing
executives. In such a process, the board of directors would select
a group of companies, such as industry rivals, to serve as a benchmarking
peer group. The option-issuing company indexes or ties the exercise
price to the benchmark group. In theory, economic and industry
factors should affect similar companies in similar fashion. Thus,
if share prices for the benchmark group rise by an average of
10% in a given year, then the option-issuing company’s shares
should rise comparably. If instead the company’s shares
rise 15%, then an assumption can be made that the executives provided
a positive 5% controllable organizational impact and, as such,
deserve additional performance-based pay. Indexed options cannot
be exercised at a profit unless the issuing company’s stock
price either outperforms, or falls less steeply than, its peer
comparison companies. Schering-Plough began using performance-based
indexed options as part (20%) of the stock-option compensation
granted to its senior executives in 2005. Other companies using
indexed stock options include Level 3 Communications, Chiron,
Capital One, RCN Corp., Perceptron, and Nuvelo. Many other companies
voted on adopting the use of indexed options in 2006, but few
of those measures were approved.
Despite the
inherent fairness in the indexing concept, many major U.S. companies
oppose it. The authors believe this is so primarily because it
would make one organization’s compensation plan less attractive
than those offered by competitors. A second possibility is that
indexing could create more pressure to “do anything necessary”
to outperform the index group and, potentially, lead to more corporate
frauds. Consider the monetary benefits that would have been awarded
to Enron executives had the company’s performance been tied
to any industry group! On the positive side, indexing would eliminate
the situation in which CEOs are granted millions of dollars of
options in a rapidly rising stock market when the companies led
by those CEOs performed worse than competitors. Indexing would
also stop the practice of repricing stock options.
Ethical
Issues
Given the
impetus for a positive “tone at the top,” as well
as the massive difference in pay between the upper and lower levels
of employees in an organization, compensation committees should
investigate how the stock option issue is judged from other, acceptable
ethical frameworks. Such perspectives can serve as the basis for
asking important questions when compensation packages are being
awarded.
It was noted
above that repricing options differently for different groups
of grantees may be viewed as unethical. Using virtue ethics to
gauge this tactic, the authors examined both the action and the
reasons for taking a particular action as follows: If repricing
is motivated by self-interest and by the company’s interest
in retaining the executive, then the action is unethical because
the remaining stakeholders of the organization are not being considered
or are being deceived by the process. The justice theory of ethics
requires equals to be treated the same way but allows unequals
to be treated differently; executives could be viewed as equals
and all others could be viewed as unequals. As such, differential
repricing between the two groups would be considered ethical and
appropriate. Consider, however, that the Organization for Economic
Cooperation and Development (OECD) and the International Corporate
Governance Network (ICGN) state that boards should treat all shareholders
of a corporation “equitably” and make certain “that
the rights of all investors … are protected” (“ICGN
Statement on Global Corporate Governance Principles: OECD Principles
as Amplified, Section II—The Equitable Treatment of Shareholders,”
www.icgn.org/organisation/documents/cgp/cgp_statement_cg_
principles_jul1999.php). The international business community,
in the form of the OECD and ICGN, provides no indication that
executives should be viewed any differently from other shareholders.
In remuneration guidelines adopted in July 2006, the ICGN stated
that repricing stock options without shareholder approval should
be considered “inappropriate” and that in “no
circumstances should boards or management be allowed to back date
grants to achieve a more favorable strike price (in the case of
options)” (ICGN Remuneration Guidelines, icgn.org/organisation/documents/erc/
guidelines_july2006.pdf).
Assessing
options repricing and backdating from an ethical theory of rights
perspective requires determining who is entitled (or has the right)
to what. Investors and creditors who have provided funds to an
organization have the right to receive accurate, reliable, and
transparent financial statements. Options backdating and repricing
either ignore or do not consider that right of those investors
and creditors, and, as such, these techniques would be seen as
unethical. Any corporate officers who are CPAs must remember that
the accounting profession’s ethics place the public interest
(investors and creditors) ahead of all other interests. Engaging
in options backdating and repricing as a corporate employee, or
an external auditor, with knowledge that such actions have taken
place, would be unethical from a professional perspective.
Options backdating
and repricing can also be viewed from a utilitarian perspective.
The decision of whether the actions are ethical would be made
by weighing the benefits to management as individuals and the
perceived benefits to the company and its shareholders (via increases
in share price) against the costs of the action and the long-term
negative effects on investors and creditors of false and misleading
financial information. From an ethical perspective, an individual
who rationalizes an unethical action designed to increase the
decision maker’s wealth by claiming that the action benefits
the company and its stakeholders has fallen victim to the rationalization
part of the fraud triangle discussed in Statement on Auditing
Standards (SAS) 99, Consideration of Fraud in a Financial
Statement Audit.
The Kantian
theory of ethics (named for the 18th-century German ethicist Immanuel
Kant) directs one to act only as if the action were to become
universal law. From this perspective, if stock option backdating
and repricing were intended to manipulate or deceive any stakeholders,
then the action would be considered a lie and could not be justified
by Kantian ethics; the ends do not justify the means.
The issues
of spring-loading and bullet-dodging can also be viewed from these
three ethical standpoints. If one accepts the fiduciary responsibility
of management to all organizational shareholders, then selectively
timing the distribution of options places executives in a better
position than other shareholders and, as such, discriminates against
nonexecutive owners. The ethical theory of utilitarianism is violated
by spring-loading and bullet-dodging because there are more market
participants who are not executives than there are those who are
executives. These two tactics also violate Kantianism: It is highly
unlikely that the populace would agree that treating one category
of market participants (executives) differently from another category
(all other investors and potential investors) would be appropriate.
In addition, if spring-loading and bullet-dodging are analyzed
from the perspective of Aristotle’s moral theory (i.e.,
an action is ethical if it is what a “virtuous” person
would do under the circumstances), it is difficult to conclude
that people of high virtue would knowingly engage in such a form
of discrimination. Thus, although these two activities are undoubtedly
legal, they are without question unethical—and the investing
public has had its fill of the lack of business ethics!
New
Reporting Requirements for Options
The manner
in which stock options are recorded and reported has been a controversial
subject since the 1972 issuance of Accounting Principles Board
(APB) Opinion 25, Accounting for Stock Issued to Employees.
More recent guidance, such as SFAS 123, Accounting for Stock-Based
Compensation; SFAS 148, Accounting for Stock-Based Compensation:
Transition and Disclosure (2002); and SFAS 123(R), Share-Based
Payment (2004), has not settled the controversy.
SEC rules
[conforming with SFAS 123(R)] now require that the entirety of
each executive officer’s compensation be shown in a single
amount and that the policies and goals of the compensation programs
be made in “plain English.” Tabular compensation presentations
must include the following:
- The SFAS
123(R) grant date and the fair value of the option on the grant
date by officer;
- The closing
market price on the grant date if that price is higher than
the option exercise price; and
- The date
that the board of directors (or compensation committee of the
board) actually granted the options, if that date differs from
the grant date.
According
to SEC Chairman Christopher Cox (testimony given concerning options
backdating, U.S. Senate Committee on Banking, Housing and Urban
Affairs, September 6, 2006; www.sec.gov/news/testimony/2006/ts090606cc.htm),
reports to investors must also describe “whether, and if
so how, a company has engaged (or might engage in the future)
in backdating or any of the many variations on that theme concerning
the timing and pricing of options. For example, if a company has
a plan to issue option grants in coordination with the release
of material nonpublic information, that [information] will now
be clearly described.” Thus,
if the new SOX section 403 disclosure rules are adhered to completely,
it is unclear how future backdating activities could occur. But
if such activities do transpire, they are significantly more likely
to occur with knowledge by and complicity of the board’s
compensation and audit committees.
The
First to Fall
The first
company to actually pay a fine in connection with backdating charges
was Brocade Communications Systems Inc. Formal charges were announced
in July 2006 and the company agreed to pay a $7 million penalty
to settle the allegations on May 31, 2007. (In April 2007, Apple
Inc.’s former CFO, Fred Anderson, agreed to pay a fine of
$150,000 and to repay option gains of about $3.5 million, but
the company itself had not been sued by the SEC.) In January 2005,
Brocade announced earnings restatements for fiscal years 1999–2004;
those restatements reduced the company’s net earnings by
$279 million.
In June 2007,
a criminal trial commenced against Brocade’s former CEO,
Gregory Reyes, who was charged with 10 felony counts of securities
fraud, including defrauding shareholders by changing stock options
dates and falsifying and forging related documents to hide such
activities. At that time, Reyes was the first executive to stand
trial, although executives at other companies had been charged
with crimes related to backdating. (Interestingly, Reyes never
backdated any options to himself, only for employees he wanted
to retain at the company.) Reyes’ lawyer took the position
that the CEO had no intent to defraud: The accounting rules were
too complex to be understood by Reyes and many others. The trial
lasted until early August 2007, and, after six days of deliberation,
the jury found Reyes guilty of all charges—apparently not
buying the “byzantine accounting” argument.
Balancing
Ethics and Incentives
Companies
that have been found to backdate options must restate the financial
statements. SEC Staff Accounting Bulletin (SAB) 99 specifically
addressed this issue by requiring that an error involving an increase
in management compensation be restated regardless of the amount.
The company’s taxable income could also be affected if restatements
require the recognition of additional compensation expense. In
turn, the option recipients may find themselves subject to an
IRS tax audit, because additional corporate recognition of compensation
expense would entail the recognition of income by the recipients.
The use of stock option pricing models required by SFAS 123(R)
could create future ethical and technical problems if those models
are based on inaccurate assumptions or variables as input to the
valuation process. The PCAOB was concerned enough about stock
option auditing to issue guidance on this subject in Staff
Questions and Answers—Auditing the Fair Value of Share Options
Granted to Employees (October 2006; www.pcaob.org
/Standards/Staff_Questions_and_Answers/2006/Stock_Options.pdf).
So much interest
and concern over stock option backdating and repricing, evinced
by so many individuals and organizations, bodes poorly for the
legitimacy of the potential motives for such actions. Such actions
cannot withstand examination under any ethical test and should
raise concern among investors, creditors, executives, and boards
of directors. Based on the outcome of the Brocade case, such concerns
have permeated the minds of potential jurors and thus the wider
public.
Stock options
were designed as a way to provide pay for performance, not to
reward poor performance by backwards-looking repricing or backdating.
Such activities undermine the incentive justification for use
of stock option plans. Executives deserve compensation packages
that provide both short-run benefits and a long-run motivation
to increase organizational value for all stakeholders. Compensation
methods that cause the tone at the top to be perceived as a cacophony
of greed should be banished from the orchestra.
Cecily
Raiborn, PhD, CPA, CMA, is the McCoy Endowed Chair in Accounting
at Texas State University, San Marcos, Texas.
Marcos Massoud, PhD, CPA, is the Robert A. Day
Distinguished Professor of Accounting at the Peter F. Drucker Graduate
School of Management of Claremont McKenna College, Claremont, Calif.
Roselyn Morris, PhD, CPA, is a professor of accounting,
and Chuck Pier, PhD, is an assistant professor
of accounting, both at Texas State University, San Marcos, Texas. |
|