Stock
Option Accounting: Defying the Usual Answers
By
Gregory J. Baviera and Larry M. Walther
Among
the initiatives set in motion by the continuing outcry regarding
corporate governance and accountability is a renewed interest
in requiring the expensing of stock options. FASB appears
resolute in its position that the “preferable”
approach to account for stock options is to expense their
fair value. Sharing this view are the International Accounting
Standards Board (IASB) and powerful voices on Capitol Hill,
including Federal Reserve Chairman Alan Greenspan and Senators
Carl Levin and John McCain. Meanwhile,
many corporate entities are choosing to expense options. The
tide appears to be shifting toward the expense-based approach—an
approach that might become mandatory.
The
Outcry to Expense
Recent
accounting scandals have moved the topic of executive compensation
to the forefront. Stock options are a substantial part of
many compensation packages. While the size of the grants
varies among industries, most major corporations use them
to some extent.
The
accounting treatment for employee stock options is generally
found in Statement of Financial Accounting Standards (SFAS)
123, Accounting for Stock-Based Compensation, and
Accounting Principles Board Opinion (APBO) 25, Accounting
for Stock Issued to Employees. SFAS 123, issued in
October 1995 after much debate, required expensing in all
but one circumstance, fixed options—the most common
form of stock option in the United States—which could
continue to be accounted for under the nonexpense approach
of APBO 25. Interestingly, FASB did not vote its conscience
in adopting SFAS 123, which would have required expensing
of all stock options; instead, FASB buckled to pressure
from constituents, including certain members of Congress.
The debate escalated to the point that FASB feared for the
survival of private sector standards-setting if it held
its ground.
Since
the fight over SFAS 123, however, the political winds have
shifted and stock options have come under intense scrutiny.
FASB and Congress have also gained an important and unexpected
new ally: corporate America. Many prominent corporations,
including Ford, General Motors, and Coca-Cola, and several
large financial firms have announced their decision to voluntarily
expense stock options. This change of heart has been attributed
to two factors. First, these companies are trying to win
favor with the investment community by their new openness.
Second, according to a recent survey conducted by Standard
& Poor’s Quantitative Services and published in
the Wall Street Journal Online, these companies will not
recognize a serious hit to earnings by choosing to expense
options.
Not
all companies have followed suit, however. Many high-tech
companies declared that they do not intend to voluntarily
expense stock options. These companies use stock options
as a major component of executive compensation; as such,
fair value expense treatment will significantly affect their
bottom line.
At
the heart of the argument for expensing options is the three-way
relationship between the employee, the entity, and the shareholders.
Granting options is not merely a rearrangement of ownership
interests, in this view, but a transaction related to the
entity. Commentators point to a number of indicators, including
the entity’s market purchases of shares to fulfill
their side of the bargain when options are exercised, the
issuance of shares that could otherwise be sold to raise
cash, and the nature of the contracting between boards and
managements. They conclude that the substance and form of
stock option grants make them more than rearrangements of
existing ownership, although they could be structured this
way in form.
The
theoretical argument against expensing stock options hinges
on the entity concept. This argument is presented in more
detail below. Regardless of one’s conclusions about
stock option expenses, the debate points up a problem in
applying the entity concept in its purest form: The transactions
of the entity should be accounted for separately from its
owners’. There may be a need to reexamine the entity
theory to expand it to include situations where the affairs
of owners, the entity, and entity employees become intertwined.
The
Entity Assumption
A basic
accounting assumption, the entity concept, circumscribes
the economic activity accounted for. The long-accepted view
is that economic substance prevails over legal form in identifying
the entity for which to account. Relevance requires that
accounting information be related to the business unit that
is substantively impacted by a transaction or event. For
example, accountants often prepare consolidated statements
for separate legal entities. Conversely, sole proprietorships
are reported upon separately and apart from the personal
affairs of the owner. In other words, transactions are attributed
to the appropriate unit of accountability.
In
the case of stock options, some proponents of expensing
confuse the legal and economic substance of the transaction,
and possibly may be unaware of the entity assumption; this
makes some of their statements and reasoning inconsistent.
For example, Alan Greenspan at the 2002 Financial Markets
Conference of the Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta said:
“[A] stock option is a unilateral grant of value from
existing shareholders to an employee.” While this
might be true in some limited circumstances, it is especially
confusing in light of Greenspan’s ardent support of
expensing stock options because the “entities”
Greenspan identified in his comment were the shareholders
and the employees, not the company.
A company
that owns its own shares does not account for them as corporate
assets but as treasury stock. When a company grants options,
it is not transferring its assets, nor is it creating a
corporate liability; rather, it is compensating the grantee
with unissued shares or treasury shares. Because there is
no asset transfer or liability creation, expensing opponents
argue that a stock option grant fails to meet the definition
of an expense as defined in Statement of Financial Accounting
Concepts (SFAC) 5, Recognition and Measurement in Financial
Statements of Business Enterprises. Instead, in this
view the existing shareholders are redistributing (either
explicitly through proxy vote approval, or implicitly by
powers delegated to the board of directors) units of ownership,
with the company serving as the conduit through which the
transaction passes (except for the option price itself,
which does accrue to the corporation upon exercise, and
the accounting for which is not at issue). Because neither
corporate assets nor corporate liabilities have changed,
total equity remains unchanged. But total equity has been
redistributed.
FASB’s
logic and corresponding conclusion approach the problem
differently: No one would argue that if a company issued
shares for cash, and gave the cash to an employee, then
the cash given to the employee should be expensed. Now,
if the same shares are instead given to an employee who
sells them for cash, all parties are put in
the exact same position. Therefore, the accounting should
be the same. Thus,
the value of the stock should be expensed. But consider
the following scenario: Suppose an entrepreneur started
a new business, owning 100% of the stock. The owner promises
a manager 10% of the stock if the business revenue exceeds
business expenses by X amount. Upon reaching X, would it
be fair for the owner to declare that no stock is due the
manager because X really means “X plus the fair value
of 10% of the stock”? (This is puzzling math, but
is exactly the same result as declaring that the value of
the stock must be included in the business expense; i.e.,
“Revenues – Expenses – Stock = Income”
is the same as “Revenue – Expenses = Income
+ Stock.”)
Everyone
is entitled to draw their own conclusion about the logic
of this outcome, but needless to say, the manager would
take issue that the entity assumption was created to separate
business income determination from capital transactions.
Incorporating the value of share redistributions, in this
view, misreports business performance. This is why certain
corporate leaders vehemently oppose the proposal to expense
stock options. To illustrate, consider an individual who
starts a business with a $1,000 investment. The business
produces a $2,000 profit and intrinsic business value of
$20,000. The business pays the owner a $2,000 dividend.
Ten percent ownership (worth $2,000) is transferred to reward
the employees. FASB would argue that the business has broken
even ($2,000 profit minus $2,000 stock award)—even
though its owner has already withdrawn more than his investment.
Stock
options are a form of compensation to employees; however,
people differ in their conclusions about whether this compensation
comes from the existing owners or from the entity. If granting
stock options is a redistribution of existing ownership
interest, then it is not a performance measurement issue
for the company. Even if options should not be expensed,
it does not follow that they should be ignored in corporate
reporting. Unfortunately, the current accounting model does
not effectively capture this transaction unambiguously.
Expansion of the approach to the entity assumption is needed.
The
Nature of Accounting
The
truthfulness and usefulness of any measurement is enhanced
by employing triangulated measures. In business, many transactions
are themselves triangulated; in the case of options, the
triangle includes the entity, the owner, and the employee.
Accounting
theory has not embraced “triangulation” measurement
concepts. In the accounting model developed over 500 years,
the trader or entity has always been regarded as the center.
This view has led to one- and two-dimensional accounting
conventions and standards. The
outcry to expense stock options is based on an attempt to
capture a triangular transaction (involving the employee,
the company, and the shareholder) in a two-dimensional accounting
model that is not capable of presenting it accurately. Accountants
must recognize and develop new tools necessary to carry
us safely beyond the horizon.
A
New Model
Strong
support for revising the current accounting model is found
in the 1991 Jenkins Committee Report. In their analysis,
the Jenkins Committee specifically targeted professional
users of business reporting. The committee determined that
“professionals generally base their decisions on superior
models and methods” and that “because of their
training and full-time focus, professionals should be better
able to articulate their needs for information.” This
focus on professional users is a critical distinction.
The
current debate appears to be targeted to a wide spectrum
of users. It is widely understood that not all professional
users require the same information; it is likely that the
same holds true for a broader scope of users. After significant
field research, the Jenkins Committee issued several recommendations
for facilitating change in business reporting. Of particular
interest is its recommendation that companies should be
encouraged to experiment with ways to improve the usefulness
of reporting, with an emphasis on key statistics and ratios.
Redirecting the focus from recognition and measurement to
the usefulness of disclosures is the key to altering the
accounting model. For example, a new statement that would
identify the degree of dilution suffered by shareholders,
and the degree to which employees have disposed of or continue
to hold their equity share, might be of great relevance
for professional users.
Our
currently accepted theory does not necessarily support either
expensing options or ignoring them. What is needed are new
theories, approaches, measures, and reports that more accurately
pinpoint the economic positioning of the parties involved
in modern business transactions.
Gregory
J. Baviera, CPA, is an IT auditor at BNSF. Larry
M. Walther, PhD, is chair of the accounting department
at the University of Texas at Arlington. |