Audit
Contracting Entities: Organizations That Might Change Everything
By
John W. Berry
A new
type of organization might change everything about auditing:
what auditors do and how they do it, even how they see themselves
as auditors. It would accomplish that by tearing down the
management wall separating auditors from the public they
are supposed to serve. It would free the profession from
the stranglehold of overlapping and conflicting interests
that has kept the auditing profession from taking its rightful
place in the financial arena. In doing so, it would clear
the way for auditors to attain the credibility, respect,
and dignity to which they are entitled.
The
audit contracting entity (ACE) is not a single organization
but a type of organization. If and when ACEs are introduced,
they will number in the thousands, one for every sizeable
corporation that is audited.
What
Is an Audit Contracting Entity?
An
audit contracting entity (ACE) is an organization independent
of management that takes the place of the board of directors
in selecting, monitoring, and compensating a company’s
auditors. In pursuit of independence, the history of auditing
has in some respects been one of kicking corporate responsibility
for monitoring audits farther up the ladder of corporate
management. The problem is that no matter how far up the
responsibility is moved, it is still management.
Few
people conversant with modern auditing would disagree that,
in an ideal world, management should not be in a position
to influence or control the auditor. During the recent crisis,
it has been proposed that the stock exchanges select the
auditors for their listed companies. From an independence
standpoint, this arrangement makes sense because it removes
management from the equation for audit contracting purposes.
The stock exchange proposal has never been seriously considered,
probably because it would result in “one-size-fits-all”
audits that would ignore the subtleties and nuances of the
individual corporations being audited.
The
ACE system falls somewhere in between the stock exchange
contracting proposal and the current system. Proponents
of the ACE concept recognize that selecting auditors should
not be a function of management at any level. Yes, the directors
should hire executives and set policies and procedures for
preparing the corporation’s financial statements.
But ACE proponents hold that if the purpose of auditing
is to perform an independent review of the statements for
the benefit of outsiders, then management should not be
able to influence or control that process.
Relevant
Outside Interests
ACE
proponents would identify relevant outside parties that
should control the audit process as stockholders not affiliated
with management, the company’s bankers and lenders
and other creditors, and potential investors and creditors
and their representatives in the credit-rating and analyst
fields who depend on the statements.
The
system does not work that way now because, prior to governmental
regulation of companies in Great Britain and the United
States in the 19th and 20th centuries, corporate management
had unlimited control over access to its books and facilities.
That control gave management an absolute veto over whatever
auditing system might be adopted. Add the fact that outsiders
with an interest in the audits had a range of interests
and it should come as no surprise that the process had been
left in the hands of management insiders. Much of that has
now changed. Power has shifted dramatically away from management.
Unfortunately, that power has shifted not to the relevant
outside interests, but to the regulators. That power is
being exercised to increase the pervasiveness of regulation
and enhance government bureaucracy rather than to excise
the impedimenta of management at the root of the problem.
The
ACE system would effect the needed change in control over
the audit process by selecting representatives of those
relevant outside interests and putting them in charge of
that process. ACEs would likely emerge at the state level
because states control the incorporation of companies and
the accreditation of professions.
To
forestall the possibility of ACEs becoming subservient to
the organizations that bring them into being, the manner
of selecting the members of the ACE boards would have to
be objective, such as random selection from authorized pools.
In New York, for example, the legislature could make ACEs
available through the State Comptroller’s office,
which would guarantee that the selection was conducted free
of bias. The legislature would set the criteria to be applied
to a request from a corporation for the establishment of
an entity on its behalf. In carrying out its function, the
State Comptroller’s office would prepare generic charters
for such entities and make them available for corporations
to use. Other charters could be made available from independent
organizations that sponsor the establishment of ACEs.
Typical
ACE Operations
A typical
ACE might have a seven-member board with staggered seven-year
terms: three members selected at random from a pool of stockholders
not affiliated with management; a fourth from a pool of
bankers; a fifth from a pool of bondholders; a sixth from
a pool provided by pension funds; and a seventh from a pool
provided by mutual funds. The number of members and their
terms would vary across companies, and the makeup of the
pools and the method for authorizing them would be set by
ACE legislation.
A corporation
could elect to use an off-the-shelf ACE or propose one of
its own. If a corporation provided an entity of its own
makeup, the designated state regulator would apply the criteria
set by the legislation and approve or disapprove it. Thus,
management would have input into the composition of the
board (the interests to be represented) but not the actual
selection of board members. The regulator’s role would
be limited to determining whether the composition of the
board was appropriate in representing the interests of those
who rely upon the audits; it might also supervise the initial
process of selecting board members to ensure that the board
is free of outside influences. Once established, the entities
could oversee future selection of board members. They would
do so in accordance with the random-selection processes
provided for in the legislation and subject to monitoring.
Entity
boards chosen in this fashion would be independent not only
of management but also of the organizations that established
them, and they would represent the interests of those who
rely on the corporation’s financial statements.
After
an entity is established (probably in the form of a special
public corporation), the members would meet, organize, elect
officers, set meeting dates, solicit bids for audit work,
select the auditors, contract for the audit, and monitor
audit work. Management would have the right to challenge
actions of the entity that it believed were not in the best
interests of the corporation. It could do so by legal action
or by appeal to a vote of stockholders not affiliated with
management.
Implementation
Issues
While
the decision to establish an ACE would be voluntary, the
parties that rely on the audits might insist on it. For
example, the SEC could set a policy requiring that registered
companies adopt the ACE method. It would be in the interests
of stockholders, who have traditionally been passive when
no opportunity was available to install this type of oversight.
The
composition of interests represented by the entities would
evolve over time to fit the purposes of the audits. Management
would tend to favor stockholder majorities to ensure that
cost was a significant consideration. Bankers and other
creditor interests and rating agencies might tend to favor
nonstockholder majorities. The SEC might develop a set of
characteristics that it would prefer or require. Whatever
the ultimate makeup of a particular ACE, it would necessarily
be more independent than a board representing solely management
interests.
ACEs’
operating expenses would probably be paid for by the corporation,
although those costs could theoretically be covered in some
other way, such as through a charge against stockholders
or a regulatory fee. Determining the remuneration for board
members might involve a provision in the entity’s
charter tied to objective yardsticks, such as the corporation’s
revenues, the number of employees, and similar elements.
Special cases might require a court proceeding.
While
the overall cost to society of maintaining ACEs would exceed
the current costs of monitoring audits through boards of
directors, the boards would be relieved of this responsibility
and their remuneration could be adjusted accordingly, partially
offsetting the cost. Compared to the hundreds of billions
of dollars lost to audit failures over the last few decades,
the cost for maintaining the ACE system might be a bargain.
Short-Term
Effects on Routine Activities
In
many cases, audits conducted under ACEs would be virtually
undistinguishable from those conducted under the board of
directors system. Where earnings and solvency are not especially
critical, and management is not under inordinate short-term
pressures, auditors are accepted as outside experts and
independent advisors whose judgments management respects
and accepts regardless of the potential bottom-line impact.
Auditors would be less inclined under the ACE system to
defer to management in minor matters, but the relatively
independent working relationships they are accustomed to
would be maintained and the final audit results would be
identical.
A person
unfamiliar with auditing might then ask, “If in many
if not most cases the results will be the same, why bother
setting up the ACE system?” The answer is that auditing
is essentially about the exceptions. While it is not unreasonable
to assume that in most cases management’s statements
are correct, outsiders want auditors to sort out the few
bad reports from the vast majority of good ones.
The
same tendency of auditors to be less deferential to management
in an environment free of undue pressure on management will
have a profound impact in other audits where those characteristics
are not present. In an Enron or WorldCom, the audit contracting
entity will have maximum impact. Free of the pressures that
management might otherwise exert, auditors will be able
to go about their business. In some situations, auditor
independence would be carried to a counterproductive extreme
and management would be plagued with frivolous complaints.
This possibility should be weighed against the extraordinary
damage to the financial markets arising from the scandals
already a matter of record, and the loss of credibility
those scandals entail.
Long-Term
Effects
Once
ACEs are firmly established, the short-term change in the
auditing environment will grow into a longer-term change
in the auditor mind-set. In persuading management to engage
them for their audits, auditors must now emphasize the positive
service aspects of their relationship to management rather
than the benefits of independence. Persuading an ACE to
engage a firm for an audit is a different matter. In dealing
with an independent entity anxious to uncover any misrepresentations,
the auditing firm will be inclined to point out situations
where the firm uncovered misstatements or misleading statements,
or its ability to ferret out fraud, especially management
fraud.
This
perspective will tend to drive the auditing firm at every
level. Within the firm, that perspective will show itself
in the treatment of colleagues and employees. Those who
uncover errors during the audit will be improving the image
of the firm in the eyes of the ACE client, and they will
be rewarded.
Another
long-term effect is the potential development of a more
concrete institutional form to represent investors’
interests and the gravitation of auditors to the center
of that institutional framework. Although auditors have
always had the skills, knowledge, and access to take the
lead in representing investor interests, their relationship
to management has (not unreasonably) resulted in their being
viewed as in management’s camp. With the freedom of
action that ACEs will give them, auditors will more likely
be recognized as the ideal party to articulate investor
concerns. ACEs will play the leading operational role in
their function of selecting, monitoring, and compensating
auditors; however, they will do so because of the independence
they bring to the function, not because they will necessarily
bring any profound knowledge of financial concepts in general
or any in-depth knowledge of a corporation’s financial
condition. Lacking the expertise that auditors bring to
their function and the specific knowledge that an intensive
examination of the company’s records and procedures
entails, ACEs will have to defer to the auditors in the
broader scheme of elaborating investor interests. We can
expect the SEC to continue in its role of looking out for
investors’ interests with respect to SEC-specific
legal compliance issues, but once an ACE system is well
established, an organization like the SEC would probably
assume a more supportive role, because the auditors will
be doing the SEC’s work on the front lines, where
they have constant, direct access to corporate management,
records, and facilities. Auditors would move to the forefront
in ensuring appropriate financial reporting and would become
the focal point in the expression of investor interests.
Many
observers have bemoaned the fact that auditors performed
nonaudit services for companies, under the theory that nonaudit
services income tends to corrupt auditors. This argument
holds some truth, but it ignores the fact that the income
from the audit itself has an even more direct potential
for corrupting the auditor. Whether the ACEs decide to limit
the nonaudit services performed by auditors or not, the
amount of work auditors would do under the ACE system would
probably increase substantially. ACEs would undoubtedly
turn to auditors not only to audit their corporations’
financial statements but to investigate other matters of
direct interest to stockholders and of collateral interest
to bondholders, bankers, and others. There is reason to
believe that the amount of auditing work required of auditing
firms would at least double because of the need for more
reliable, objective information concerning major operations
and acquisitions.
Management
might resent the introduction of ACEs, as it would be natural
for any group to resent the loss of a prerogative to which
they are accustomed. Ultimately, though, management will
probably adapt positively to the new paradigm. Management
should eventually appreciate being freed from a conflict-laden
responsibility that has brought them much grief. They should
also enjoy the greater weight that will attach to a “clean
bill of health” from auditors over whose selection
they had no influence.
Potential
Impact on Auditing Concepts
Some
changes that might occur would be mundane on the surface
but fundamental in their implications. For example, to whom
is the audit opinion letter to be addressed? The board of
directors? Probably not. The opinion would presumably be
addressed to the entity commissioning the audit and to which
the auditors report.
As
for testing, the present system may have been subconsciously
tailored to provide justification for prospective failures.
The range of industries over which failures have occurred
and the range of major firms that have been implicated indicate
a more general flaw with the design or application of major
testing procedures. As for the degree to which internal
control testing has been emphasized over substantive testing,
this move toward the abstract may represent an unconscious
search for a safe harbor in situations where auditors may
be ambivalent about discovering exceptions. Something like
this may have been involved in a recently reported major
audit that did not uncover a $300 million overstatement
of cash.
Another
area that might come into the spotlight is the performance
of sample testing at the expense of judgmental testing.
The advantages of sample testing in quantifying and comparing
particular tests are well known. But what about the auditor’s
skills, honed through years of experience and involving
more variables than any computer could process? The dividing
line between areas subjected to judgmental testing and those
where sample testing is being used may need to be redrawn.
As
for peer review, which many observers herald as a cure-all,
its operation might have a sinister aspect. For example,
a lone holdout among the Big Four against what it perceives
to be a poor testing approach could be brought into line
by “peer pressure” through peer review. And
if that could happen, what chance would midsized firms or
sole proprietors have to resist standards set by the larger
firms and, ultimately, the profession? Could peer review
have the paradoxical effect of being a mechanism for enforcing
a descent toward the lowest common denominator?
From
an outsider’s standpoint, perhaps the most significant
overall difference between auditing under management oversight
and under ACE oversight is that in the latter context auditors
will be more inclined to view the substance of financial
statements over their form. If management attempts to stretch
a particular rule to fit its predilections, an auditor operating
in an ACE environment will probably be more concerned with
the impression the presentation leaves on the reader than
with whether a particular rule is technically acceptable.
There
is also the matter of the systematic study of audit failures.
It is one thing to read about an audit failure in the newspapers
and have the auditor involved punished by the courts. Having
such audits formally studied by auditing experts with a
view to assessing the causes of those failures is another
matter. Would accountants, with the financial community’s
endorsement, support a system for monitoring audit failures
where such events would be formally reviewed by an independent
group charged with establishing the failure’s causes?
These
and other questions about testing might well be raised when
a profession that has plodded along with testing standards
that are themselves fairly resistant to testing becomes
confronted with an environment where firms openly compete
to demonstrate the superiority of their testing approaches.
The result might be a ringing endorsement of present standards;
then again, it might not.
Thinking
the Unthinkable
The
ACE concept allows us to expand beyond the strictures of
our current conceptual framework. Under ACEs, would the
financial community and auditors themselves come to see
the auditor’s role not as one of verification, but
as one of preparation of statements using management’s
as their guide. This is a radical change in a theoretical
sense, but it might not differ much from how statements
are often prepared in the real world. In the process, the
concepts of qualified and adverse opinions would be left
behind. The financial community would probably be inclined
to give greater credence to statements independently prepared
by auditors than to those issued by management.
If
the statements were issued by the auditors, would they still
be “fairly presented”? If one is examining someone
else’s statements, it might be reasonable to use the
expression “fairly” to indicate that a particular
presentation is an acceptable one among a number of reasonable
interpretations. If, however, the auditor prepares the statements
and has concluded that they accurately depict the company’s
financial situation, it may be more accurate to describe
the presentation as “correct” or “appropriate”
rather than merely “fair.” If the auditor prepared
the statements, they should reflect that auditor’s
best possible interpretation of the underlying financial
activity rather than merely a fair choice among many.
A further
fundamental issue could also be raised by ACEs. Whether
one is expressing the opinion that statements are “fairly
presented” or “appropriately presented,”
the affirmative opinion itself implies a lengthy and complex
mental process. If such is the case, can the opinion really
be a collective process? Can a firm really speak of “our
opinion”? The procedures followed by the designated
decision-maker can be reviewed by peers at the firm as to
their form, but the substance of the opinion is necessarily
limited to that particular person. Under the circumstances,
if the ultimate responsibility for preparing the financial
statements moves from the entity being audited to the audit
firm, identifying the particular person who makes those
decisions becomes important. At some point it may seem more
precise to have the auditor in charge formally identified
and required to sign the report, with the auditing firm
recognized in a supporting capacity. Of course, the current
wording could be abandoned in favor of wording stating that
nothing had come to the attention of the firm to indicate
that the statements were not fairly or accurately presented,
but that would not be an affirmative opinion.
Other
questions could be raised with regard to legal liability
and professional ethics. Would the legal liability applied
to audits change from fraud to negligence? Might the legal
liability of an auditor for an audit failure be limited
by legislation in a situation where a systematic study of
that failure, endorsed by the state regulator, showed that
failure was due to causes beyond the control of the auditor?
Furthermore, would auditor ethics need to be completely
rewritten? Would the end product look more like attorneys’
ethics than what we are accustomed to?
Awakening
the Sleeping Giant
The
auditing profession has fallen into disrepute because of
the series of scandals that has recently plagued it. These
scandals can be viewed as resulting primarily from ethical
failures on the part of individual auditors. But the ethical
failures must be judged within the broader framework of
how the institution is organized. We must ask ourselves
whether auditors in general are being put into situations
that are a slippery slope into ethical lapses. Forced to
choose among dauntingly abstruse economic concepts, with
a wide range of reasonable interpretations available, and
knowing that one’s standard of living may rest on
a decision that upsets client management, a formidable trap
awaits. Is it reasonable to set a standard of such heroic
proportions? And does such a standard merely have the effect
of clearing the path to the top for the least scrupulous
and the most morally indifferent? Is something more fundamental
afoot?
In
the broad institutional sense, the root cause of audit failures
may be viewed as arising from a serious flaw in the institutional
structure in which auditing operates. Within that structural
framework, the operating mechanism that governs the auditing
process is the auditor-management relationship, in which
the operating interests of management are represented while
those of unaffiliated stockholders, bondholders, bankers,
creditors, and prospective investors and creditors are not.
This misalignment of interests at the operational level
is a serious flaw that might be the root cause of not only
recent problems but also those that have plagued auditing
since the beginnings of modern auditing in England and Scotland
early in the 19th century.
In
that context, it is interesting to read the minutes of a
meeting of the Scottish Institute, as reported in The
Accountant on June 26, 1897. All of the participants
that responded to a paper presented at that meeting on the
subject of independence took the position that as auditors
they lacked independence because they were beholden to the
directors who chose them and compensated them. One participant
declared, “Under the present system, the independence
of the auditor is a mere farce … although many shareholders
imagine they appoint the auditor—[laughter] he [is]
the nominee of the directors and under the control of the
directors.” Another said, “It [is] perfectly
plain that even the most conscientious auditor, whose appointment
lay in the hands of the directors, might allow certain things
to take place which otherwise would not take place.”
Clearly, the problem that brought Andersen down is not a
new one.
The
ACE system deals with the independence problem by installing
an operating mechanism in which the relevant interests are
properly aligned. The practical impact is that auditors
are given incentives that directly encourage them to uncover
false and misleading assertions and to verify ones that
are true. Auditors are still called upon to act in an ethical
manner, but they are not asked to choose between maintaining
their ideals and maintaining their careers.
It
has been argued pessimistically that auditors are a dying
breed on the brink of irrelevance. That is a depressing
commentary on how things have been allowed to deteriorate,
considering that auditors enter the profession as the best,
the brightest, and the most idealistic. But it is not surprising,
given auditors’ relationship to management, because
as that relationship develops, these brilliant minds become
trapped in a competition to accommodate management, a competition
to reach the lowest common denominator. No wonder the auditing
profession has stumbled into failure after failure. If the
stranglehold that management has over auditors can be broken,
just the opposite might occur. The slumbering giant might
awaken. The auditing profession might throw off its shackles
and take its place at the forefront of the financial information
industry, protecting the vital interests of investors and
other members of the public in the process.
John
W. Berry, CPA, is a partner of Berry & Berry,
CPAs, in Franklinville, N.Y.
|